Paul A. Samuelson
(1915 - 2009)
"What we know about the global financial crisis is that we don't know very much."
——Paul A. Samuelson
**
The discipline of economics lost
one of its giants in the death of Paul Anthony Samuelson, an Institute
Professor Emeritus and Gordon Y Billard Fellow at MIT, who, right from 1932,
enlivened the waiting “sleeping beauty of political economy” with his “kiss of
new methods, new paradigms, new hired hands and new problems” till he died at
his home in Massachusetts at the ripe age of 94.
Paul Samuelson was born
in Gary, Indiana, US, in 1915. He earned a bachelor’s degree in
1935 from theUniversity of Chicago. Being “never one to blindly
accept adult advice”, he, despite the advice of his mentors inChicago to
join Columbia University, moved to Harvard, of course, “by
miscalculation”, to obtain a master’s in 1936 and a PhD in 1941. In 1940, when
Harvard offered him instructorship, he accepted it, but later, knowing
the 'revealed preference' of Harvard University, switched over to the
Massachusetts Institute of Technology when they invited him as assistant
professor, and later in 1947 became the professor of economics. In a span of
seven decades, he transformed MIT into an economics powerhouse—all by virtue of
finding early in his life such a kind of work that “has been pure fun”.
As Paul Krugman felt, it is hard
to comprehend the full extent of Samuelson’s greatness, for as against the
usual craving of every economist to write at least one seminal paper, a paper
that fundamentally alters the way economists think about an issue in one’s
lifetime, he wrote dozens. “He provided a unified set of principles under which
several economic fields could be linked”, said Jagadish Bhagwati
of Columbia University.
His prodigious brilliance became
evident right from his nineteenth year when he audited a graduate course taught
by the legendary Chicago economist, Jacob Viner, pointing out his
blackboard errors. And when such phenomenal brilliance is married to his
passion for economics, which reflects aptly in what he once said, “I was reborn
when at age 16 on January 2, 1932, 8.30 a.m., I walked into a Midway lecture hall
to be told about Malthusian population”, the outcome cannot be less rewarding:
his PhD thesis submitted to Harvard university had resolved the then prevailing
contradictions, overlaps and fallacies in the classical language of economics
by unifying and clarifying them using mathematics as a tool. And such
revolutionary output cannot but, as Samuelson himself said, confront the fellow
economists who had been practicing “mental gymnastics of a peculiarly depraved
type” like “highly trained athletes who never ran a race”. Indeed, there was an
unconfirmed anecdote doing rounds in those days that highlighted Samulson’s
exceptional grasp of economic theory: it says that “at the end of Samuelson’s
dissertation defense, Schumpeter turned to Leontief and asked, ‘Well, Wassily,
have we passed?’”
Samuelson, on the one hand
enjoying the benefit of being the sole protégé of the polymath Edwin Bidwell
Wilson (the only protégé at Yale University of Willard Gibbs) at Harvard by way
of getting “essential hints that helped in the development of revealed
preference…” and on the other hand surprised “at the little help he could
garner from the scores of leading mathematicians and physicists like Birkhoff,
Quine, Ulam, Levinson, Kac, or Gleason, who had no motivation to waste their
time getting intuitively briefed on someone else’s model in the idiosyncratic
field of mathematical economics”, and at the same time “self-taught
[mathematics] by spending himself in the library stacks on mathematics”,
brought relevant mathematics into economic thinking to present a unified
mathematical structure for predicting how businesses and households would
respond to changes in economic forces, how changes in wages would affect
employment, and how changes in tax rates would affect tax collections.
With his acumen to use mathematics as a language to explain how consumers react
to changes in prices and income, he came out with his theory of ‘revealed
preference’ in microeconomics. Pushing the mathematical analysis to a higher
plane of sophistication, he used comparative statics and dynamics to propose
the ‘correspondence principle’—the theoretical link between the behavior of
individuals and the aggregate stability of the entire economic system—which he
later applied to successfully explain the dynamic stability of general
equilibrium.
He had developed a mathematical
model to study the impact of trade on different groups of consumers and
workers. His famous Stolper-Samuelson theorem established that competition from
imports of consumer goods from underdeveloped countries is all set to drive
down the wages of low-paid workers in industrialized countries. He even stated
that the US economy could get hurt if productivity of its trading
partners rose. In his interview to William A. Barnett in Macroeconomic
Dynamics he categorically said: “Free trade need not help everybody
everywhere.” Yet, he remained an advocate of open trade proclaiming that it is
the higher productivity that helps but not ‘protectionism’. Driven by such
philosophy, he supported the North American Free Trade Agreement, and also
signed a letter supporting expanded trade with China. Nonetheless,
Stolper-Samuelson theorem became the intellectual lever in the hands of the
opponents of the globalization to drive home their argument. It is no wonder
therefore for Stiglitz to say, “Some of the work he [Samuelson] did—Trade
theory and international economics—is more important today than it was then.”
Samuelson developed the commonly
known “Bergson-Samuelson social welfare functions”, followed by formulating the
theory of ‘public goods’—goods that can be offered effectively only through
collective or government action. For instance, Air force is one such public
good— it is non-exclusive and also eliminates rivalry among consumers, which means
that the amount of security that citizen ‘A’ consumes does in no way reduces
what citizen “B” is entitled to. It otherwise means that public goods cannot be
sold in markets because there is no incentive for the consumer to pay
voluntarily; instead they look for a free ride. He had successfully tied
“public goods” with neoclassical theory.
He had also formulated the modern
theory of production. His theory of capital, though contentious, is well
received. In association with Solow, he initiated the analysis of dynamic
Leontief systems. He developed linear programming for the use of central
planners or corporates to estimate how to produce preset levels of goods and
services at the least cost. Introducing “surrogate” production function, he
became the main adversary of Joan Robinson in the ‘Cambridge Capital
Controversy, but being a man who “hate[s] to be wrong” and “hate[s] much more
to stay wrong”, he subsequently relented graciously.
In macroeconomics, his
multiplier-accelerator macrodynamic model—rudimentary mathematical business
cycle model that defined the inherent tendency of market economies to
fluctuate—that could show how markets can magnify the impact of, say, one
dollar increase in foreign investment into a several dollar increase in total domestic
income, to be followed by a decline, is rightly famous. So is the case with the
presentation of the Philips curve jointly with Solow. Similarly, he is much
acclaimed for popularizing the ‘overlapping generations’ model along with
Allais that was later used for many applications in macroeconomics and monetary
theory—many scholars used the model to study the functioning of the Social
security system and the management of public debt.
Later, directing his attention to
financial markets, he put together mathematics to predict stock price
movements. Indeed, his work on speculative prices is a pointer to the efficient
market hypothesis. His work on ‘diversification’ and the ‘lifetime portfolio’
is equally well known. It is these mathematical analyses that constitute the
platform from which Merton and Scholes have come up with their Nobel Prize
winning ‘Option Pricing model’ which is extensively used by the Wall Street to
trade on derivatives. He is recognized as one of the founders of modern
finance.
Over and above all these
astonishing mathematical conclusions and economic theorems, Samuelson—whose
“Chicago trained mind resisted tenaciously the Keynesian revolution; but reason
won out over tradition and dogma”—is known more for his marrying Keynes’ The
General Theory’s main paradigms pragmatically and opportunistically to
conventional economics and ultimately developing the neoclassical synthesis. He
had almost a life-long debate with his neighbor from Chicago, Milton Friedman—a
monetarist and a staunch believer that governments do not know the welfare of
people— on how even modern free market economies could get trapped in liquidity
traps during periods of depression needing pump-priming from government or
tax-cuts, in addition to easy monetary policy, to come out of them. Indeed,
Samuelson, who had the real experience of the boom-bust economic effects of
World War I, and the Great Depression, taking Keynes as his intellectual hero,
articulated all along that economic stability and growth required government
intervention. In fact, he walked his talk: as adviser to the newly elected
President Kennedy, Samuelson told him that the nation was heading into a
recession and so he should push through tax-cut to head it off. The government
had of course implemented his advice and the economy bounced back. Even the
recent global financial crisis vindicates Samuelson’s strong faith in Keynesian
philosophy.
Samuelson, best known for his
methods and innovations but not politics, had been invited by two presidents
—Kennedy and Johnson—to join the Council of Economic Advisers, but as Solow, a
Nobel Laureate in economics who sat next to Samuelson in MIT for 50 long years,
once observed, Samuelson, in his preference for “the role of an idea person”
rather than being “a person for an everyday routine, for committee meetings and
that sort of thing”, declined their invitation saying he did not want to put
himself in a position in which he could not say and write what he believed.
Ultimately, it is this singular
asserted focus of him that enriched his life with a long list of
accomplishments: won David A. Wells prize in 1941 for writing the best doctoral
dissertation—The Foundations of Economic Analysis—at Harvard University, which
in the words of Kenneth Arrow, “is a treatise … that has so much originality in
every part that it is entitled to be accepted as a thesis”; was awarded the
John Bates Clark medal in 1947, given annually by the American Economic
Association to the outstanding economist under the age of 40 on his publishing
the book, Foundations of Economic Analysis, one of the grandest
tomes that helped revive Neoclassical economics and launched the era of the
mathematization of economics; he was the first American to be awarded Nobel
prize in economics in 1970 by the Swedish Royal Academy “for the scientific
work through which [he] has developed static and dynamic economic theory and
actively contributed to raising the level of analysis in economic theory”; and
finally the National Medal of Science, America’s top science honor, in 1996,
for his “fundamental contributions to economic science, specifically general
equilibrium theory and macroeconomics, and to economic education and policy
over a period of 60 years.
Samuelson was the most prolific
writer of his profession. Besides five books, he had published 550 academic
papers on topics ranging from the theory of production to consumer choice
to international trade to finance to growth theory, setting the agenda
for generations of scholars. His Econimics, first published in 1948,
has become the best selling economic text book of all time. Paul
Krugman, who examined the original edition of 1948 before launching
himself on writing a new book, said that "it is extraordinary work,
lucid, accessible without being condescending and deeply insightful."
According to him, Samuelson's discussions on speculation and monetary policy
are particularly striking, for it brings Keynesian economics to
America——which is perhaps, more relevant today than ever. No wonder, it has
been translated into many world languages and sold four million copies so far.
Some economists consider this book, currently into its 19th edition, as his
great contribution.
Paul Samuelson’s was a life of
fulfillment: during his long journey as a teacher, he simply “transformed
everything he touched: the theoretical foundations of his field, the way
economics was taught around the world.…” His contribution to the field of
economics is aptly summarized by Robert M. Solow, his colleague for 50 years at
MIT, thus: When economists “sit down with a piece of paper to calculate or
analyze something, you would have to say that no one was more important in
providing the tools they use and the ideas that they employ than Paul
Samuelson.”
Despite such celebrated
accomplishments, Samuelson, it is said, preached and practiced
humility—economists “have much to be humble about.” His MIT economics
department became famous for collegiality. It reflects in Samuelson’s
article—“International Trade and the Equalization of Factor Prices” in The
Economic Journal: “I have been teaching this theorem [Ohlin-Heckscher theorem]
… for a number of years. When recently a student challenged this result, I
availed myself of the usual teacher’s prerogative of referring him to the
textbook … But doubt once provoked is not so easily lulled: neither the class
nor its instructor found the relevant passages quite satisfactory,” and of
course, he went ahead with research to plug the gap. Isn’t it a lesson for
teachers how to practice teaching?
The only way we can honor the memory of this great man is by
practicing the values he practiced, and by praying: May such souls revisit the
planet at least once in every century!
GRK Murty
I very much like what you have written about my friend and coauthor, the great Paul Samuelson.
ReplyDeleteThanks a lot Dr. William A. Barnett. I am so happy it could satisfy you...
ReplyDelete