The Chinese
President Mr. H U Jintao landed in India with an entourage that consisted of
top executives of many companies, besides political heavyweights. Reports
indicate that the visit is meant for unveiling several new initiatives, notable
among them could be forming an “energy-investment alliance” to jointly explore
overseas oil fields and give a boost to their bargaining power to buy foreign
energy assets, work out a strategy to strengthen negotiation-leverage at the
World Trade Organization, besides framing more robust commercial relationships.
There were also indications in the press that the scope for Free Trade
Agreement (FTA) may also be discussed. No surprisingly, the idea of FTA with
China has evoked negative response from many quarters, including academia.
FTAs are
“agreements among two or more parties in which reciprocal preferences are
exchanged to cover a large spectrum of parties’ trade in goods.” Although
historically free trade agreements are expected to expand markets and enhance
economic efficiency T N Srinivasan, Professor of Economics, Yale University,
argues that theoretically, FTAs are inferior to multilateral trade
liberalization. FTAs, being private agreements between two countries, the
administrative mechanism, available under WTO that guarantees smooth flow of
trade within a rule-based trading system, is not available for administering
and settling disputes under FTAs. It is
thus not feasible under FTAs to enforce anti-dumping rules, subsidiary
restrictions, etc.
What is more,
free trade agreements are not only antithetical but also engender a lot of
problems in terms of defining and policing rules of “origin of goods”. Such
rules are quite essential since tariff preferences are accorded only to goods
actually produced in the partner country but not to the goods from the rest of
the world that could make an entry through the partner country with the lowest
external tariff. The rules of origin (ROSS) that govern preferential treatment
are invariably complex. According to Prof. Srinivasan, they only provide ample
opportunities for bureaucrats to make non-transparent and opaque protectionist
measures by manipulating the rules. For instance, the rules of origin under the
FTA between the US and Singapore said to run to almost 203 pages. Despite these
disadvantages, FTAs are mushrooming all over that, too, more out of
non-economic considerations.
It is true that
our GDP grew at an average annual rate of 6.2% during 2000-04 while that of
China at 10.6% and it is also true that such high growth means increased demand
for goods and services. This is already evident from the fact that the
bilateral trade between India and China grew from $338 mn in 1992 to $13.6 bn
by 2004 and it is projected to touch $100 bn by 2015. This obviously poses a
question: When economy of both the countries is in such a pink, why not an FTA,
which is a potential tool for bettering the economic cooperation between India
and China.
But there is embedded risk in it: All said and done, our economic miracle though real is just confined to the highly specialized IT services, outsourcing and similar areas. China, by virtue of its efficient manufacturing abilities has already become a manufacturing hub of the world, and thus stands better globally integrated than India. Unlike China, we are not a main exporter of consumer goods. China’s share in the world exports under manufactured goods is 6.5% while ours is a dismal 0.9%. Even in terms of value-addition under manufactured goods, China is far ahead of us with a share of 8.5%, while we are languishing at a minuscule share of 1.4%. Around 64% of our exports to China are in the form of primary goods—iron ore etc. while 50% of our imports from China are value-added manufactured goods. Over and above, the ruling import tariff on manufactured goods in our country stands at around 17-19% while it is 5 to 7% in China. In view of these inequalities, Indian exporters can gain no substantial advantage under the proposed FTA vis-รก-vis Chinese exporters.
But there is embedded risk in it: All said and done, our economic miracle though real is just confined to the highly specialized IT services, outsourcing and similar areas. China, by virtue of its efficient manufacturing abilities has already become a manufacturing hub of the world, and thus stands better globally integrated than India. Unlike China, we are not a main exporter of consumer goods. China’s share in the world exports under manufactured goods is 6.5% while ours is a dismal 0.9%. Even in terms of value-addition under manufactured goods, China is far ahead of us with a share of 8.5%, while we are languishing at a minuscule share of 1.4%. Around 64% of our exports to China are in the form of primary goods—iron ore etc. while 50% of our imports from China are value-added manufactured goods. Over and above, the ruling import tariff on manufactured goods in our country stands at around 17-19% while it is 5 to 7% in China. In view of these inequalities, Indian exporters can gain no substantial advantage under the proposed FTA vis-รก-vis Chinese exporters.
Secondly, under
the proposed FTA, our domestic manufacturers are likely to face a threat to
their survival. According to one estimate, China has lower cost in many
products than India and thus we have lost market share in third markets to
China and this trend is likely to continue in the future unless we catch up
with China in costs. That aside, under the proposed FTA, imports from China
will become cheap which is sure to impact sales of domestic manufacturers
adversely. The increased competition from China under FTAs is certain to
threaten the survival of some of the rural production units in India, notable
among them being raw silk and other agricultural produces. As we are already
suffering from a none-to-happy performance under rural economy, adjusting to
the proposed FTA may prove costly.
On any count, it
may not be an appropriate time for us to rush for FTA with China. Instead, as
Prof. Srinivasan opined, it is better that along with China, we focus our
efforts in ensuring that the multilateral process of trade liberalization under
WTO get started soon. We may also jointly work for the repeal of the article
XXIV of GATT/WTO on customs unions and FTAs and get a new clause inserted
whereby, trade preferences of any regional or other agreements are extended to
all members of the WTO.
(December, 2006)
No comments:
Post a Comment