Riding a bicycle
has never been easy, particularly for a new practitioner. But hope is the spark
of life. The bumped new cyclist does not give up. He gets up, jumps onto the
seat again, and starts pedaling afresh. But there must be someone around, may
be an uncle or a brother, to hold it from behind so as to ensure that the
bicycle doesn’t fall while the kid is pedaling it forward.
After all, if
the ultimate goal of the World Trade Organization (WTO) is to maximize the “gains
from trade” for all its member countries through the best possible allocation
and enabling the best use of world’s finite resources under a well-designed
multilateral trading system that is governed by a set of agreed upon rules, one
must confess that WTO is a kid—a kid just learning riding a bicycle.
No doubt, WTO
has passed through many curves, overcome many bumps, and indeed, bagged success
too. Yet, as Fred Bergsten of the Peterson Institute for international
economics theorized, trade liberalization is like riding a bicycle. And, the
bicycle theory states that one cannot stand still. Unless one moves forward,
the bicycle will lose its equilibrium and the rider will fall off it.
And that’s just
what happened in Geneva. After nine days (and nights) of intensive talks, the
trade ministers of different countries managed to clear 18 out of the 20 agenda
items set before them by the untiring WTO’s Director General, Pascal Lamy, yet
failed to ‘converge’ on the remaining two items namely—Special Safeguard Mechanism
(SSM) in the context of import of food items into developing countries and
subsidies to agriculture in the developed world, particularly the US, perhaps,
under the pressure of their respective domestic compulsions. There was no uncle
or brother behind the bicycle to hold it from falling, or if there was, they
had coolly taken their hands off as the kid was pedaling. The net result is:
ministerial talks in Geneva have failed again.
No point in
entertaining a blame game. It doesn’t matter whether it is the US or the
combine of India and China that was responsible for the fall of the bicycle,
for both had taken their hands off the bicycle. What therefore matters most
here is: How serious are the developed countries in enhancing ‘reciprocal altruism’? Or, how committed are
they to “minimize the dominance and maximize the use of reciprocity that
ensures gain in trade, making everyone in the game better off?”
After all, it is
the basic instinct of mankind “to trade, to barter, to exchange one thing for
another.” Thus, it becomes essential that the mutual reciprocity of trade
should become an act of mutual and enlightened self-interest in pursuit of the
“gains from trade”—direct gains such as economies of scale, lower production
costs, lower consumer prices, broader consumer choices, and bigger markets; and
indirect gains such as improved efficiencies among domestic manufacturers owing
to increased competition, transfer of technology, and high level of innovation,
leading to continuous improvement in technology. Interestingly, as John Stuart
Mill observed, it is the intellectual and moral effects of trading which are
more important than even that of economic gains.
As against these
basic requirements, what happened in the last week of July in Geneva was the
failure of the developed world to show solidarity with the concerns of the
developing countries, that too, when the stakes involved under the conflict is
just one-tenth of 1% of global GDP. Incidentally, when the Doha round talks
started, agricultural liberalization was an issue of the developed world, but
today the US is demanding significant expansion of access to the agricultural
markets of the developing countries. Nor could it display a shining example of
its commitment to trade liberalization: it has increased its allocation for
farm subsidies from the current level of $9 bn to $14.5 bn, which is sure to
hit the exports of sub-Saharan cotton growers badly.
Looking at the
prophesied difficulties of developed countries in selling the idea of genuine
liberalization—reducing their farm subsidies that are required to encourage
agricultural exports from developing countries—one wonders how they are
expecting the developing countries to sell the ‘structural adjustments’
required in terms of opening up of markets for their agricultural products,
that too, at the cost of the welfare of their teeming millions of small and
marginal farmers. Moreover, in today’s context of soaring food prices, it is
all the more difficult for developing countries to effect structural changes
unless there is a matching gain elsewhere. Indeed, basic economics dictate that
as new supplies from external world make inroads into traditional domestic
markets of developing countries, there arises a dire need for increased opportunities
for exports from these countries to offset the pressure towards more
protectionism.
It’s not that
this simple equation is not known to the developed countries, but apparently
the principle of ‘reciprocity of altruism’ is given a go-by and instead, they
are obviously preferring the art of ‘dominance’ as a tool to garner trade gains
for themselves. And the victim is ‘multilateralism’ at the expense of which
bilateralism has in the recent past become rampant. Which means, today’s world
is more tilted towards open economy. All that is required is to keep pedaling,
so that the bicycle moves forward equally benefitting all the 145 countries.
(September, 2008)
No comments:
Post a Comment