The rupee, as a
sequel to the government’s announcement of fresh restrictions on External
Commercial Borrowings (ECBs), turned volatile in the intra-day trading and
ultimately closed at Rs. 40.52 registering a loss of 12 paise, which amounts to
around 1%—all in a day’s trading on 9th August.
Market reactions
aside, what is more important here are the restrictions per se and their impact
on the macroeconomic fundamentals. As a result of the restrictions imposed,
companies can now raise ECBs for rupee expenditure only up to $20 mn, that too,
with the prior approval of the Reserve Bank of India. Corporates are also
required to park such borrowings overseas till the rupee expenditure
materializes. The current restrictions have two implications: one, the need for
the nod of the RBI disables companies from timing their ECB borrowings to their
advantage; and two, for anything beyond $20 mn, companies have to approach the
local market. The ECBs above $20 mn can, of course, be availed of only for
incurring permissible expenditure in foreign currency.
Palpably, the
motive behind the current restrictions is to strengthen the hands of the
Reserve Bank of India in imposing stricter discipline under its ongoing
conservative monetary policy. Admittedly, ‘plenty’ of foreign capital is always
a problem to manage. In the last six months alone, it is reported that Indian
companies have borrowed $19.13 bn from global financial markets as against
$13.58 in the whole of 2006. Similarly, inflow through FIIs has also gone up.
The inflow of
foreign exchange in excess of a country’s absorbing capacity poses many
problems. One such major problem is the appreciation of domestic currency. Such
appreciation is more acute when the central bank withdraws from its market
intervention, as is currently happening. Rupee has, thus, appreciated in the
recent past by 9% creating ripples in the corporate corridors, for it made
Indian exports less competitive in the global markets besides eroding their
profit margins. An excess inflow of foreign exchange also results in the rise
of reserve money, and broad money, which indeed rose by 60.7% and 64.3%
respectively by March 2007. Such rise in monetary base automatically makes more
bank credit available. That aside, if
much of such credit goes towards creation of assets—reports indicate that real
estate loans have gone up by 155% in 2005 and 66% in 2006—it may, over a period
of time, result in asset ‘price bubbles’. Cumulatively, all this creates
inflationary pressure in the economy. And no political economy of a country can
afford to let these developments go unchecked.
Against this
backdrop, the present restrictions imposed on ECBs sound pretty laudable. There
is, however, a flip side to it: the domestic interest rates are already
relatively high and in such a scenario, when the blue chip companies move
towards domestic banks for their financial needs, it tends to push the interest
rates further northward. In the light of the recent hike in CRR, the interest
rate scenario is all set to further worsen. This increased cost of capital will
obviously get translated into higher sales price of the end products of
industrial activities. To that extent, goods become less competitive not only
in the export market, but also in the domestic market where imported goods are
today posing a threat to the domestic manufacturers owing to the drastic
reductions in tariff. It means fall in demand for the industrial goods and
services, of course, with a time lag. That is why some economists fear that the
present restrictions on ECBs may have an adverse impact on the GDP.
There could be
another unintended consequence of these restrictions. Owing to the increased
cost of rupee borrowings, blue chip companies may, instead of investing in
their domestic expansion/diversion projects, resort to overseas acquisitions
through borrowings from global financial markets so as to keep their growth
prospects intact. Such overseas acquisitions may not, of course, affect the GDP
per se, but is certain to impact domestic employment opportunities, which means
loss of opportunity to improve the buying power of the domestic consumers.
There is yet
another dimension to these restrictions: so long as the growth rate continues
to remain around 9%—for which there are strong indications—the inflow of
foreign exchange will continue at the current levels, if not rise. In this
context, a school of economists argues that if at all the flow of foreign
capital is to be contained, it should be more through restricting FII
investments by way of imposing some kind of tax rather than limiting ECBs.
There is a logic in this argument: availability of capital at lower interest
rates, including fully hedged borrowing, vis-à-vis domestic interest rates
makes Indian businesses more competent to withstand global competition. On the
other hand, FII flows are always speculative in nature and are known to move
around the emerging markets exclusively with a profit motive. They are known to
run away from emerging markets at the slightest provocation, as is happening
today.
In view of these
ground realities, the restrictions presently imposed on ECBs can, at best, be
of a short-term nature and what really needs to be done is increasing the
absorption capacity of the foreign capital inflows by the country.
(September,
2007)
No comments:
Post a Comment