Rationalists see a rationale in the behavior of exchange rates. And they have immense faith in their own ability to theorize economic behavior. Hence, they postulate theories to define exchange rate behavior. They all sound logical in depicting the rationale. But markets are manned by ‘herds’. However rational one may be individually, no sooner he becomes a herd-member, he lets go rationality and sways with the herd. The net result is: exchange rate theories remain as theories and markets swing in their own (ir) rationality. Yet, there is a method in that madness…
Economists
often refer to exchange rate as the single most important price in an open
economy that has tremendous influence on many other macro level monetary and fiscal
decisions of countries across the globe. Guessing a correct Exchange Rate has,
therefore, become a critical input for market players. There are however two
predominant ways of explaining the behaviour of exchange rates: one, to look at
exchange rates from the perspective of its supply and demand position, and,
based on it, to analyze the behaviour of major market participants, and two, to
study the behaviour of aggregate variables such as expected inflation rates,
interest rates, etc. and accordingly take a view on market movement. Against
this backdrop, let us attempt to trace the impact of the various macro-economic
fundamentals and behaviour of market participants on the behaviour of exchange
rates.
1. Balance
of Payments
Balance of Payments is the summary of all international
transactions between residents of one country with the rest of the world
community. It represents the demand for and supply of foreign exchange, which
ultimately determines the value of the domestic currency. Factors like rate of
growth in GDP, savings and autonomous capital inflows from overseas markets,
etc., also impact exchange rates. Exports, both visible and invisible,
represent the supply side of foreign currency, while imports create demand for
foreign exchange. When the balance of payments position of a country is
continuously at deficit, it implies that the demand for the foreign currency is
more than its supply and, therefore, its currency depreciates in value. On the
other hand, if the balance of payments position is surplus, the currency gains
in value as we are witnessing with Rupee in the recent past.
Box 1: Balance of Payments – Basics
|
Balance of payments
is an accounting statement that summarizes all the economic transactions
between residents of a country and residents of all other countries. Currency
inflows are recorded as Credits and outflows as Debits. There are three
balance of payments categories:
Current Account : Records flows of goods, services and
transfers.
Capital Account : Shows public and private investments and
lending activities – indicates changes in foreign financial assets and
liabilities.
Official Reserves Account : Measures
changes in holdings of gold, foreign currencies – Reserve assets – by
official monetary institutions.
Balance of payments statement is based
on double entry book-keeping. Every economic transaction recorded as a credit
brings about an equal and offsetting debit entry and vice versa. For e.g. if
a foreigner sells a machine to an Indian resident the debit is recorded to
indicate an increase in purchase by India; a credit is recorded to
reflect an increase in liability to a foreigner.
Current Account
The balance on
current account reflects the net flow of goods, services and unilateral
transfers (gifts). It includes exports and imports of merchandise (trade
balance),military
transactions, and service transactions (invisibles). The service account
includes investment income (interest and dividends), tourism, financial
charges (banking and insurance), and transportation expenses (shipping and
air travel). Unilateral transfers include pensions, remittances, and other
transfers for which no specific services are rendered.
Exports are usually valued on f.o.b.
basis and Imports at c.i.f values. The net difference between the credits and
debits is known as balance on merchandise trade account – which could either
be deficit or surplus.
Invisibles
Traditionally, trade
in physical goods is separated from trade in services. Credits under
invisibles consist of services rendered by residents to non-residents, income
in the form of interest, dividend, royalties on patents and designs whereas
debits consist of payments to foreign technical consultants, revenue
contributions by Government of India to UN establishments, flight charges
made to non-residential steamships, airlines, etc.
The net balance between the credit and
debit entries under the heads Merchandise, Nonmonetary gold movements and
Invisibles taken together constitute what is called Current Account deficit
or Current Account surplus.
Capital Account
It indicates changes
in the country’s foreign financial assets and liabilities. These transactions
are usually grouped under sub-heads – Private, Banking and Official.
Private transactions
Includes long-term
loans received by private companies, investments by foreigners in the equity
of the Indian companies, repayment of long-term loans by Indian corporates,
etc.
Banking Capital
Covers foreign
financial assets and liabilities of commercial banks that are privately owned
or government owned. Assets consist of balances held by the banks in their
foreign branches or correspondent banks abroad and rupee assets representing
overdrafts granted by Indian banks to branches of foreign
banks/correspondents. Similarly, liabilities consist of Indian banks’ debit
balances in the foreign accounts and credit balances held by foreign banks
with banks in India.
Any increase in asset is a debit while a decrease in asset is a credit.
Official Capital Flows
Consists of transactions
relating to foreign financial assets and liabilities of Govt. of India and
Reserve Bank of India:
Credit entries under Loans consist of drawls by Govt. of India or loans
granted by foreign governments and debits consist of loans disbursed by Govt.
of India to foreign governments.
Balance of
Payments statistics are regularly compiled, published and are continuously
monitored by companies, banks and government agencies because they have both
short-term and long-term implications for a host of economic and financial
variables impacting exchange rates and interest rates of the country.
|
Current
account, one of the constituents of BOP, has a relationship with exchange rate
behaviour. When a country experiences current account deficit, it issues claims
to the assets acquired and in the process supplies more of its currency than
what the market demands. This situation leads to excess demand for domestic
currency as more goods and services are imported than exported. This imbalance,
in turn, leads to eventual depreciation of the domestic currency to eliminate
the excess supply in a floating rate environment. This depreciation makes
exports more competitive and consequently improves current account. By a
reverse argument, current account surpluses recede as the exchange rate
strengthens, again bringing about an automatic correction in the exchange rate.
The foreign
exchange reserves that are held by central banks are in terms of foreign
currencies, gold, and other investments, SDRs, etc., indicate the ability of a
country’s central bank to maintain its currency at a desired exchange rate.
Countries with a surplus in their current account usually build-up reserves to
enjoy the benefits of a strong currency which is anti-inflationary, besides
making imports cheaper and thereby compel domestic manufacturers to price their
products at current price. But technically speaking in a system of truly
floating rates, there is no need for the central banks to maintain reserves
since any disequilibrium between supply of and demand for foreign exchange
tends to settle on its own through changes in the relative values of
currencies.
To better
appreciate the role of governments in the foreign exchange market, one has to
understand the complexity of multiple objectives being pursued by the
governments. It is also essential to appreciate that pursuit of one objective
leads to the sacrifice of the other. For instance, if creation of high
employment is the objective, governments usually practice a combination of
expansionary monetary policy and fiscal deficit. This measure leads to a high
level of inflation that, in turn, impacts the balance of payments, which means
exchange rates. The relationship between macro-economic factors, current
account and exchange rate behaviour is summarized below:
2. Inflation
It has multi-dimensional effect on the exchange rate
movement, for it not only moves exchange rates but also interest rates. For
that matter, one simple channel that links interest rates with exchange rates
is the effect of inflation. Since nominal interest rates depend on expected
inflation, and nominal exchange rate depends on relative rates of foreign and
domestic inflation, an inflation shock will affect both nominal interest rates
and exchange rates. Inflation shocks can usually be expected to lead to a
negative co-relation between nominal interest rates and exchange rates. For
example, if money supply increases, increased inflation will become the norm.
To the extent higher inflation is built into inflation expectations, nominal
interest rates will tend to rise. And, if inflation exceeds inflation in
foreign countries, the nominal exchange rate will tend to fall.
Similarly,
deflationary policy could lead to a negative relationship between interest
rates and exchange rates. A reduction in the inflation that leads to lower
inflation expectation, could tend to reduce nominal interest rates. And, if
inflation rate is lower than foreign inflation rate, domestic products will
become more attractive in international markets resulting in forex inflows that
make the rupee tend to appreciate. Similarly, increase in inflation increases
the domestic prices leading to exports becoming less competitive. As a result,
exports fall; with it the demand for currency declines resulting in the decline
of external value of currency. To sum up, it is the relative rate of inflation
in the two countries that causes changes in exchange rates.
3. Interest
Rates
As seen under Fisher relationship, changes in real
interest rates are translated directly into change in nominal interest rates.
Secondly, it is the changes in real interest rates that alter relative
attractiveness of the domestic or foreign investment opportunities. This, in
turn, causes movements in real and nominal exchange rates. For instance
consider a FII with the choice of investing in Indian or in his domestic
assets. The exercise of the choice rests on two critical inputs:
- One, a comparison between relative real interest rates, and
- Two, as the assets are denominated in different currencies, investor could also consider differences in the real exchange rates since it affects the ultimate return.
So, any
expected appreciation of the real value of the Rupee represents an expected
capital gain and adds to the Indian real return, making an overseas investor to
prefer investment in India.
Similarly, any expected depreciation of real value of the Rupee represents a
capital loss and lowers the Indian real return.
Generally,
market forces should equalize the real returns to investment in the two
countries[1].
But usually, market forces equalize the real returns to investments in the two
countries. That means –
Indian real
interest rate |
+
|
Expected
appreciation of
real exchange rate |
=
|
Foreign real interest rate
|
In other words,
if the Indian real interest rate is higher than the foreign real interest
rates, the market usually expects the real exchange rate to depreciate. Thus,
the expected deprecation of the real exchange rates offsets the higher real
interest rates and the real return from Indian investment equals the foreign
real return. To sum up, the expected appreciation or deprecation of the Rupee
is directly related to the real interest rate differential in the two
countries.
Box 2: Real Exchange Rates
|
A general expression
for the effective real exchange rate of country i(Ei) is
given by.
Where,
Pi measures
the domestic price level in country i;
P*j
the foreign price level in country j;
Sij is
the relevant nominal exchange rate (defined as foreign currency per unit of domestic
between country i and j); and
is the weight of country j in country i’s effective exchange rate index.
As such an
increase in Ei implies
that the currency has appreciated, or alternatively that it has become less
competitive.
|
Source: Rebecca L
Driver and Peter F Westaway, Concepts of equilibrium exchange rates, Working
paper no.248, Bank of England.
|
In this
framework, an increase in the Indian real interest rate will lead to the
increase in the real exchange rate and the nominal exchange rate. A higher
Indian real interest rate increases the attractiveness of Indian assets,
leading to an increase in the demand for Rupee denominated assets which, in
turn, lead to appreciation of the real exchange rates. Then, for given price
levels at home and abroad, the nominal exchange rate also tends to rise.
There is yet another
way of looking at the whole relationship: an increase in the Indian real
interest rate leads to an increase in the real exchange rates. But as per the
equation given above, the total real return from the Indian asset must equal
the foreign real interest rate. Hence, a rise in the Indian real interest rate
relative to the foreign real interest rate must lead to an expected
depreciation of the real exchange rate. Therefore, if we assume that the real exchange
rate is constant in the long run, the market simply expects the real exchange
rate to depreciate to future, for which real exchange rate has to appreciate
today. William Branson (1985) said: “what must go down in the future (an
expected depreciation), must go up today (the current real exchange rate)”[2].
4. Money
Supply
Like the price of any commodity, the price of money too
is determined by the laws of supply and demand. When the supply of money is
less than the demand for funds, interest rates increase. Similarly, when the
supply of funds exceeds the demand, the interest rate decreases. It is the
central banks of the countries that usually control, of course within certain
limits, the growth of the country’s money supply. This is often done through
changes in the discount rate. However, what is not clear is the impact that a
change in money supply will have on the level of interest rates. For example,
in periods of relatively low inflation rates with ample idle capacity, what is
perhaps needed for the market to absorb the increase in money supply is lower
interest rates, as is being witnessed currently in our country. On the other
hand, if inflation rates are already high, the increase in money supply calls
for increase in interest rates to contain rising inflation. Thus, it is the
‘situation’ that defines the impact of money supply on interest rates and, in
turn, the exchange rate behaviour but not ‘money supply’ per se.
5. Capital
Movements
Short-term movement of capital may be influenced by the
interest rate structure. If interest rate rises, there will be an inflow of
foreign capital and as a result of increased supply of foreign currency, the
exchange rate of the rupee will rise. If interest rate falls, there will be
outflow of capital and therefore, the exchange value of the rupee will fall.
Bright
investment climate and political stability may encourage portfolio investments
in the country. This leads to a higher demand for Indian securities leading to
an appreciation of the rupee. Poor economic outlook, on the other hand, may
lead to repatriation of investments leading to decreased demand for Indian
securities which, in turn, depreciates the value of rupee.
6. Private
Speculations
The purchase of foreign exchange for profiting from an
expected fall (rise) in the domestic exchange rate – which in the market
parlance is termed ‘speculation’, is considered the prime cause for much of the
volatility in exchange rates. In other words, volatility is stemming from the
actions of speculators rather than from changes in the factors that determine
the equilibrium exchange rate. For instance, a fall (rise) in the exchange rate
leads speculators to think a further declaim (increase) is imminent. Driven by
this belief they sell (purchase) domestic currency and thus drive its price
further down (up). In view of this, speculation is considered a destabilizing
force that magnifies deflections in exchange rates[3].
There is,
however, another view: speculation is considered a stabilizing force. To make
profits, speculators must buy when the exchange rate is below its equilibrium
level and sell when it is above its equilibrium level. Thus profitable
speculators push the exchange rate towards equilibrium rather than away from
it.
7. Central
Bank’s Intervention
Ever since floating rate regime commenced in 1973,
world’s central banks, including RBI, have intervened frequently and at times
forcefully in the forex market to influence the path of their respective
currencies’ movement/stability as also in the interest of their monetary
management. Policy makers have a variety of tools at their disposal to
influence the exchange rate movement viz. – monetary policy; and control on
capital movement etc. But the immediate reaction of central banks to any market
dislocations is to intervene either in the spot market or forward markets or in
both, at the same time.
Though
intervention in the spot market serves the objectives of Central Bank, such
sudden intervention makes market makers’ job/task that much more difficult. Its
intervention is simply based on the philosophy that whenever the demand and
supply of any foreign currency puts pressure on the exchange rate, there arises
a need for the central authority to satisfy the excess demand or to remove the
excess supply by intervening and putting into the market some of the foreign
currency from its own stocks or by taking the excess into its stock.
Similarly, it
also intervenes in forward market, though it is a topic of considerable
dispute. One argument is that it is essential for the central bank to intervene
in forward markets for managing domestic interest rates and thereby inflow and
outflow of money. At times, it may also intervene on a substantial scale to
reduce the pressure of speculation on the home currency, but this is often
doubted by market players. Its main disadvantages are: it tends to make the
task of the speculator easier by cheapening the cost if he is mistaken, without
seriously reducing the profit if he is right and second, it puts tremendous
burden on the intervening central bank in terms of cost. Admittedly, if the
speculation is unjustified, there is no doubt of profit for the central bank in
the operation but, if the speculation turns out to be justified, the central
bank may have to really bleed.
Sterilized vs.
non-sterilized intervention from the Central Bank is another critical factor
that has far reaching effect on exchange rates. The general purpose of each
intervention of Central Bank is to increase market demand for one currency by
increasing the market supply of another. In the process, it leads to increase
in the supply of domestic currency and all other things held constant, it leads
to high inflation. Therefore, such intervention not only changes the exchange
rate but also the inflation rate and, in turn, interest rates. So an intervention
has to be always through open market operations so that the excess liquidity
from the system can be absorbed by way of issuing Treasury Bonds, etc. So a
sterilized intervention is quite imperative.
All said and
done, Central Bank intervention operations do still exert a short run impact on
exchange rates. In benign market conditions, intervention can exert a marked
influence on the trend of exchange rates. But under turbulent conditions like
what was witnessed during the Asian crises, when massive flows of speculative
capital moved from one group of currencies to another, virtually no concerted
intervention effort of any central bank can succeed in holding the line.
8. Exchange
Rate Movement in the Short-run
The National Bureau of Economic Research carried out a
study on "How do UK-based Foreign Exchange
Dealers Think Their Market Operates?", addressing three issues[4]:
- The microeconomic operation of the foreign exchange market, like trading techniques and mechanisms;
- Traders’ views on the relevance of fundamentals in explaining the changes in exchange rate determination and its strengths in predicting the future exchange rate movements; and
- Importance of microstructure factors in studying rate changes.
It conducted a
primary survey of 110 UK-based foreign exchange dealers during March-April 1998
and the results are very interesting:
- There is a huge and significant shift from fundamental to non-fundamental factors.
- There is a unanimous belief that fundamentals are irrelevant in intra-day trading.
- There is a belief that news (32.8 percent out of 110 respondents), bandwagon effects (29.3 percent) and speculative effects (25.3 percent) are more important in the intraday market,
- Only 0.6 per cent felt that fundamentals are useful in intra-day trading.
- As the horizon lengthens the use of fundamentals rises, but with more risks.
- Speculative forces which traders measure from the order flows (synonym of effective demand) through the market were highly ranked in intra-day trading and that is the only factor perceived to play a significant role in both intra-day and medium-term trading.
It thus becomes
evident that in intra-day and short-term trading, macro theories on exchange
rate determination are of less use for dealers. Similarly, long-term
predictions are also not of much use as dealers perceive that they need to face
more risk in long run trading. It is therefore necessary to capture the impact
of speculative forces on the intra-day and short-horizon business in the
foreign exchange market.
In financial
market literature, to study speculation and uncertainties, researchers usually
apply the market microstructure theory. It deals with the behavior of
participants in asset markets and the effects of information and institutional
variables – such as technology, price information, the matching of buyers and
sellers, optimal dealer pricing policies, “news” and transaction costs;
non-synchronous trading, etc on the performance of the market.
The microstructure theory basically consists of two
models:
- Inventory model – aims at optimizing the problem as the dealers’ objective is to maximize the expected profit per unit of time. It emphasizes the control of inventory fluctuations through price adjustments to avoid bankruptcy and failure at the end of dealing. It also explains the relationship between the transaction cost and bid-ask spreads. But failure occurs in this model whenever the dealer runs out of either inventory or cash.
- Information model is based on adverse selection problems; explains the behavior of market prices through information content of trading activities. Since there is asymmetry of information between the dealers, their behaviour in deciding the price will be different; it explains ways to arrive at the equilibrium market price in the presence of asymmetric information.
Looking to
these developments in the global markets, there is a lesson to be learnt: international
banking divisions of banks must have research wings for proper predictions of
intra-day and short-term movements in the exchange rate to help dealers trade
even in a thin market and with small spreads.
We have studied forex markets, their
structure, players, dealing mechanics, exchange rate behaviour, underlying
theories, and the role of Central Banks in exchange rate management. Now from
this platform let us move on to examine the impact of foreign exchange exposure
on the cash flows of companies and how foreign exchange risk is hedged.
- Excerpts from Currency Market Derivatives, GRK Murty, IUP Books, Hyderabad, 2006.
***
[1] By Craig S. Hakkio, Interest Rates and Exchange Rates – What is
the Relationship? – Economic Review,
November 1986, Federal Reserve
Bank of Kansas City.
[2] See Willam H. Branson, “Causes of Appreciation and Volatility of
the Dollar.” The US Dollar – Recent
Developments. Outlook and Policy
Options, proceedings of a conference sponsored by the Federal Reserve Bank of
Kansas City. August 21-23, 1985, and Craig S. Hakkio and J. Gregg
Whittaker.“The U.S. Dollar – Recent Developments. Outlook and Policy Options.”
Economic Review, September/October 1985. Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City,
pp. 3-15.
[3] Douglas K. Pearce – Alternative Views Of Exchange Rate
Determination. Economic Review, February 1983; Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas
City.
[4] NBER Working Paper, 7524. How do UK-based Foreign Exchange
Dealers Think Their Market Operates?’ ... Yin-Wong Cheung, Menzie D. Chinn Ian
W. Marsh, February 2000.
No comments:
Post a Comment