In the recent
past, our budget—much to the delight of many—has become less of significance
and more of a ritual, a mere statement of annual accounts. Which, indeed, what
it is. But this year it has become the
talk of the town.
This animated
interest has been engendered by the Finance Minister’s proposal to waive
completely all agricultural loans disbursed by scheduled commercial banks,
regional rural banks, and cooperative credit institutions up to March 31, 2007
to marginal farmers having landholding up to 1 hectare and small farmers of 1-2
hectares that remained overdue as on December 31, 2007 and which remained
unpaid until February 29, 2008. He has also proposed a one-time settlement
scheme to other farmers whose loans are overdue on December 31, 2007 and which
remained unpaid until February 29, 2008, under which a rebate of 25% will be
given against payment of the balance of 75%.
This Rs 60,000
cr waiver scheme has become the center of the debate. Many have dubbed it as
mere palliative, for it has not touched the core of the problem. Indian
agriculture, the mainstay of livelihood for 65% of the population—as the Prime
Minister observed—is plagued by four deficits: “one, the public investment and
credit deficit; two, the infrastructure deficit; three, the market economy
deficit; and four, the knowledge deficit.” He further concluded that “taken
together they are responsible for the development deficit in the agrarian and
rural economy.” That being the reality, and there being no real attempt to
bridge any of these deficits, it is no exaggeration to say that the current
waiver scheme cannot really alter the plight of farmers, certainly on a
sustainable basis.
Again, the
scheme is meant only for the institutional borrowers, while those farmers who
have borrowed from traditional moneylenders at exorbitant interest rates have
to bear on as the silent sufferers of the burden of debt. It is these farmers,
who—overburdened by the debt—are committing suicides, and the scheme thus means
nothing to them. There is another argument, which, of course, is right: since
the scheme is available only to those farmers whose landholding is not
exceeding 2 hectares, it won’t relieve the distress of farmers hailing from
dry-land tracts—where the landholding is usually above the prescribed limit,
though the yield and the resultant economic returns from such tracts are much
less vis-à-vis the farms of similar size, or even of lesser size, from
irrigated tracts—for they are highly vulnerable to frequent droughts and other
weather-related setbacks.
Some have even
questioned the scheme on the grounds of ‘moral hazard’: they say that it has
punished the farmers who were honest in repaying their loans, while rewarding
the defaulters. It is also argued that such waivers by the government would
only vitiate the loan-repayment culture in the country. Intriguingly, such a
waiver, when announced in the budget that precedes an election year, is more
prone to not only lose its credibility, but also set a bad precedent.
True, all these
arguments are valid and have their own place. For, can anyone afford to ignore
the fact that ‘pro-growth and pro-business orientation’ of the government to
ensure economic growth doesn’t mean leaving “many others out in the cold”? For
instance, in the common parlance of a lending bank, a farmer with a few or no
assets under his belt, is a high credit risk. It therefore quotes them high
risk-premium, which means, higher interest rate. That is the paradox of the
system: a poor farmer who is in dire need of money does not get it easily,
while a rich man with the least need for money gets it at a cheaper interest
rate and also easily, for he is of less credit-risk. This keeps the poor farmer
poor, perpetually needing borrowed capital for tilling his land, while the rich
becomes richer. Secondly, an overdue farmer-borrower is always considered
ineligible for fresh loan, which means he cannot cultivate the land next
season. It is these hard realities that compel one to take a positive view of
whatever little good that the waiver scheme can do for the farming community.
Even otherwise, a narrow commitment of the government to ‘growth’ alone can
distort the quality of democracy by creating socio-politico-economic
disturbances.
Looking to the
enormity of disquiet being suffered by the agrarian society, one gets a feeling
that what the government did is just inadequate. Intriguingly, based on a study
that they have carried out on Indian banks, Robin Burgess and Rohini Pande have
said: “One clear thing that we do learn from this paper is that coercion is
needed to expand formal credit into backward rural areas and to force banks to
lend to poorer individuals,” for the rural branch network expansion has
increased secondary and tertiary sector output, besides increasing
non-agricultural employment suggesting “a need to reconsider rural banking as a
mechanism for attacking poverty.” Taking a cue from this, the government
should, at once, revamp the rural credit delivery system by creating a pan-India
institution by funding it through budget meant exclusively for lending to rural
population.
All things
considered, so long as the degradation of man by poverty is not solved, one
tends to conclude that waivers of this nature cannot go waste. For, “the poorly
endowed in the distribution of wealth that chance had made” are most worthy of
utmost indulgence. And, a civilized society cannot afford to be apathetic
towards its inmates.
(April, 2008)
No comments:
Post a Comment